US EUROPE AFRICA ASIA 中文
Opinion / Op-Ed Contributors

How best to fight secular stagnation

By MICHAEL SPENCE (China Daily) Updated: 2016-09-19 07:47

How best to fight secular stagnation

A Chinese worker processes steel at a factory in Qingdao city, East China's Shandong province, July 1, 2016. [Photo/IC]

Much of the world, especially the advanced economies, has been mired in a pattern of slow and declining GDP growth in recent years, causing many to wonder whether this is becoming a semi-permanent condition-so-called "secular stagnation". The answer is probably yes, but has limited utility. There are, after all, different types of forces that could be suppressing growth, not all of which are beyond our control.

Many of the growth-destroying headwinds that we currently face would be difficult, if not impossible, to counter in the near term without endangering future growth and stability. The result of these persistent conditions can be called "secular stagnation one" (SS1).

The first indication that we are experiencing SS1 relates to technology. If we are, as the economist Robert Gordon argues, experiencing a slowdown in productivity-enhancing technological innovation, long-term potential growth would be constrained.

A second condition supporting SS1 is rooted in the impact of heightened uncertainty-about growth, job security, policies and regulations, and the many developments that could affect any of those factors-on investment and consumption.

With future demand far from guaranteed, private investment has been declining in many countries, including, most recently, China. The same goes for household consumption, particularly in the advanced economies, where a larger share of consumption is optional (for example, replacing consumer durables, traveling and eating out at restaurants). And it seems that a reversal in these trends will not arrive anytime soon.

Debt is the third indicator of SS1. Households, corporations, financial institutions, and governments are all facing balance-sheet constraints, which it seems plausible to assume, are holding back expenditure and investment, elevating savings, and contributing to a broadly deflationary environment.

Actions aimed at supporting deleveraging and balance-sheet repair-such as recognizing losses, writing down assets and recapitalizing banks-carry longer-term benefits but short-term costs. Indeed, balance-sheet repair takes time, especially in the household sector, and produces an unavoidable drag on growth.

The picture is somewhat bleak. But there's a more precise question: Is there a set of policy responses that could, over time, increase the level and quality of growth? The answer again seems to be yes. This suggests we are also facing another type of secular stagnation: "secular stagnation two" (SS2) that is dictated by our unwillingness or inability to implement the right policy mix.

A key element of that policy mix would focus on tackling rising inequality. While the forces fueling this trend-especially globalization and progress in digital technology-will be difficult to counter fully, their adverse effects can be mitigated through redistribution via the tax and social-security systems.

Moreover, monetary policy, which has been shouldering much of the burden of recovery since the 2008 global economic crisis, must be rethought, because years of ultra-low interest rates and massive quantitative easing have not increased aggregate demand sufficiently or adequately reduced deflationary forces.

But raising interest rates unilaterally carries serious risks, because in a demand-constrained environment, higher interest rates attract capital inflows, thereby driving up the exchange rate and undermining growth in the tradable part of the economy. Given this, advanced-countries' policymakers should consider imposing some controls on their capital accounts (much as successful emerging economies do).

A third priority should be to strengthen fiscal responses, especially with respect to public-sector investment. Europe, in particular, is paying a heavy price for under-using its fiscal capacity-a decision that has been driven by the political unpopularity of debt and fiscal transfers.

There are more areas where countries should consider reforms, including tax policy, inefficient or improper use of public funds, impediments to structural change in product and factor markets, and mismatches between the reach of global financial institutions and the capacity of sovereign balance sheets to intervene in case of financial distress.

SS1 will make addressing SS2 much more difficult. But that is no reason to delay action in the areas where policy can make a difference. Just as our past policy choices helped generate the SS1 we face today, failure to implement policies aimed at tackling SS2 could create a much more intractable and potentially unstable situation tomorrow.

The author, winner of the Nobel Prize for economics, is a professor of Economics at New York University's Stern School of Business and a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution.

Most Viewed Today's Top News
...
主站蜘蛛池模板: 免费无遮挡无码视频在线观看| 国产精品自在线拍国产手青青机版| 久久国产欧美日韩精品免费| 欧美日韩免费在线| 免费的a级毛片| 羞羞视频网站免费入口| 国产在线观看一区二区三区四区| 相泽亚洲一区中文字幕| 在线天堂av影院| xxxxx做受大片视频免费| 成人精品一区二区三区校园激情| 久久网精品视频| 欧美xxxx喷水| 亚洲天堂电影在线观看| 沉伦柳淑云漫画3d| 伊人久久大香线蕉电影院| 精品国产综合区久久久久久| 国产一二在线观看视频网站| 黄色aaa大片| 国产欧美亚洲一区在线电影| 伊人色综合久久天天人守人婷| 在线天堂av影院| a级国产乱理伦片在线观| 好男人社区神马在线观看www| 中文字幕在线不卡精品视频99| 日本www高清| 久久亚洲私人国产精品va| 日韩字幕一中文在线综合| 亚洲AV无码AV制服另类专区| 欧美、另类亚洲日本一区二区| 亚洲国产精品毛片AV不卡在线| 正在播放国产乱子伦视频| 亚洲综合色成在线播放| 男男gay做爽爽的视频免费| 公和我做好爽添厨房| 精品无人区乱码麻豆1区2区| 四虎成人国产精品视频| 色多多成视频人在线观看| 国产亚洲av综合人人澡精品| 青青国产成人久久91| 国产又色又爽又刺激在线观看|